It is understandable that the top macro
theorists who were tasked with explaining the financial crisis didn't
measure up to the challenge. The current generation of
macro-economists grew up on New Classical Macroeconomics, a movement
founded in the 1970s in response to the apparent "failure"
of Keynesian policies to jump start the economy during the
stagflation crisis. This new school of thought sought to derive
macroeconomics from classical micro economics. In terms of
describing individual choice and real exchange, classical micro is a
highly successful theory. However, it is wholly unequipped to
address issues which affect money-production economies, and clings to
the quaint notion that money is "just a veil" which
facilitates barter. However, eight years after trouble in the
financial sector put the world on a lower growth trajectory, the idea
that in the long run money and finance don't matter for growth, and
therefore can be abstracted away when formulating theory, is the
intellectual equivalent of sticking one's head in the sand.
Unfortunately, the refusal of the
economics profession to develop an accurate account of finance has
led policy makers astray. The recently release 2016 Long Term Budget
Outlook from the CBO makes the audacious claim that the US economy
will be five percent smaller in 2046 than it would be if the national
debt were reduced as a percentage of GDP. The mechanism by which
this supposedly occurs is that households and firms would spend more
on government bonds and less on productive investments. The
government and private sector would also "compete" for
funds, and a large public debt load would thus crowd out the funds
available for investment.
Prima Facie, it's a convincing
story which quickly unravels upon further examination. First, the
so-called "loanable funds" approach where a fixed quantity
of savings is allocated by the banking sector to productive
investments has been all but abandoned by monetary theorists. Rather,
than "lending out" reserves, banks simply credit the
deposit accounts of borrowers. The bank thus takes on a deposit
liability and acquires a loan as an asset. When the bank deposits
are used by the borrower to make a purchase, settlement occurs
between banks with reserves at the central bank. If the lending bank
falls below its regulatory reserve requirement, it borrows reserves,
which the central bank supplies on demand and at a specified price.
(The Fed Funds rate in the US, the cash rate in Australia, ect.) No
banker checks to see if he has money in the vault before he lends.
Rather, as put by the great Canadian economist Basil Moore, "Banks
make loans, and then look for reserves elsewhere."
If the Fed or other central banks did
not fix interest rates but rather the quantity of liquidity in the
banking system, the Neo-classical account of bank lending would hold.
Banks would be reserve constrained in their lending activities, and
borrowers would ultimately be competing for the funds of savers. In
order for the market to reach equilibrium, the rate of interest would
rise and fall with the demand for funds. However, modern banks
operate in exactly the opposite manner. The rate of interest is
fixed, and quantity of reserves is allowed to vary.
The significance of this arcane feature
of money market structure has been over-looked precisely because it
occurs in no other domain of the economy. In the short run at least,
the quantity of any specific commodity is fixed and its price varies
so that markets clear. However, suppose that the government had the
magical power to create and destroy cell phones at will, and used
this ability fix the price of a cell phone at one hundred dollars,
regardless of market demand. If demand for phones rose, the
government would create new phones to stop the price from rising, and
if demand fell, it would destroy phones to stop the price from
falling. In this fantastical world, the use or consumption of phones
by one agent, even the government itself, could never crowd out the
use of cell phones by another agent. But on the money market, this
dynamic is not fantasy but reality. The naked truth, well understood
by virtually all central bankers, is that nobody has to "save"
so that others can borrow. An army of savers did not abstain from
eating 500,000 ice cream cones off the dollar menu at McDonald's so that Mr. X
could by his house.
But the US government does not borrow
from banks, rather it sells securities. So could it somehow "use
up" money held outside the traditional banking system? No.
Traditional commercial banks acquire short term Treasury securities
precisely in the same way they make loans. But most long term bonds
are held outside the banking sector. However, a vast network of
'shadow banks' exists which ultimately borrows from the same elastic supply
of reserves (again, ultimately supplied b the Fed) that banks do to
finance security positions.
So the dreaded crowd out can never
occur on the liabilities side of the private sector's balance sheet.
What about on the asset side? Specifically, if the US Treasury
issued much more long term debt than the private sector wished hold,
longer term yields would have to rise so that the bond market reached
equilibrium. If investors could earn high returns in risk-free
government bonds, they would probably rebalance their portfolios
towards government debt and away from productivity enhancing
investments in R&D, plant, and equipment. In the long run, this
would slow growth. However, here it is crucial to remember that the
US government, as the sole issuer of the US dollar, has a monopoly on
risk-free dollar denominated financial assets and thus controls their
quantity and availability in the market place.
This was demonstrated during the
various rounds of quantitative easing implemented by the Federal
Reserve. By replacing interest bearing long term bonds with the
ultimate short term asset, reserves at the Fed which at the time
yielded a paltry 25 basis points, the Fed created a scarcity of long
term risk-free investment outlets. This caused bond yields to fall,
which in turn made holding bonds less attractive to investors, who then rebalanced their portfolios towards riskier assets.
If juicy yields on government debt
ever threatened to cause investors to allocate too much of their
portfolios towards Treasurys and not enough towards investments in
the real economy, nothing prevents the government, either through QE
or debt buybacks, from bringing down longer term yields by issuing
more short term assets. Conversely, in an over-heating economy
"reverse-QE", where the government retires short term debt
by issuing long term debt, could be used when increases in the
Federal Funds rate fail to result in higher long term rates. (As was
the case from 2004-2006).
In sum, the size and composition of the
Federal Government's liabilities is a policy tool, not a policy
objective. Larry Summers recently criticized the CBO for its report
on infrastructure, but prefaced his remarks by calling the
institution a national treasury. I think the CBO does an adequate
job of scoring specific bills, but a rather poor job on macro-oriented
analysis. But who can blame them? When you are navigating with an
outdated map, its easy to end up in the ditch.