Acknowledgment:
I thank J.W. Mason and Arjun
Jayadev for
inspiring this paper. Their work related to this subject can be
viewed here.
All policy arguments
rely on underlying assumptions. Therefore, the debates between policy
wonks often center around fundamental worldview. This paper seeks to
avoid that trap. Often times, it is possible to reach the wrong
conclusions even if one starts with correct assumptions. Although I
disagree with mainstream views on fiscal policy, I am going to take
the mainstream assumptions about government debt as given. In what
follows, I show that the policy conclusions drawn by most budget
groups and professionals are exactly the opposite from what is
correct. In fact, even under mainstream assumptions, proper
analysis actually supports a heterodox view of budgeting and
fiscal policy.
From my interactions
with budget hawks I have determined that two key assumptions
underline their arguments. First, there is some debt to GDP
boundedness constraint. This can be formulated in various ways.
Under its strictest form, the debt to GDP ratio can never exceed a
certain level. We can relax this constraint along either levels or
time. Relaxing the constraint with respect to level, it might be
technically possible to
breach the danger zone level, but severe negative economic
consequences ensue. Relaxing this constraint along a temporal axis,
it might be possible to temporarily breach the danger zone level, but
over an infinite time horizon, debt to GDP must converge below
some finite level. While
I haven’t fully worked it out (and this post is meant to spur
discussion) I do not believe the particulars of the debt to GDP
constraint matters for the analysis which follows.In
any event, the calls to stabilize the debt to GDP ratio by various
budget groups has been remarkably consistent over the years.
The
second main assumption is
that government debt and government money are not perfect
substitutes. This can be observed in various blog posts by groups
like the CRFB. Specifically,
In explaining his
earlier comments, Donald Trump argued that the federal government
would never have to default because it could always print money. In a
mechanical sense, this is true: because the US has its own currency
and monetary policy, it can print money to buy bonds if investors are
unwilling to buy debt at all or only at very high interest rates
(assuming that the Federal Reserve is willing to print the money to
do so). Of course, there are clear limits to this policy, and running
up large amounts of debt and financing it by printing money would
cause a jump in inflation….
Budget hawks mostly content that deficits financed by bonds aren’t inflationary per se. Money financed deficits are inflationary, and replacing bonds with reserve balances (QE) is inflationary, and if done on a large scale would result in hyper-inflation. Monetary policy is therefore the sole determinant of inflation in economies where no money financed deficits are allowed. If we take monetary policy as where the central bank sets interest rates, the rate of inflation is a decreasing function with respect to the level of the monetary policy rate. (Rate hikes, ceteris paribus, reduce inflation and vice versa)
Again,
I want to make it abundantly clear that for purposes of this
analysis, I am not discussing the soundness or problems with these
assumptions. Rather, I am stipulating that they hold and examining
the policy implications. The intellectual exercise might seem
useless to some, especially since I disagree with the conditions I
outlined above. However, from a purely
policy perspective, (not theoretical) it can bridge a great divide
between heterodox and mainstream fiscal views precisely because the
mainstream draws the wrong policy conclusions even if their
assumptions are assumed to be true.
Fiscal
Policy under the Mainstream View
The fiscal authority must set spending and taxing to level over time
where the debt to GDP ratio never exceeds the hard ceiling. (A
popular number often proposed is 100 percent of GDP, but the actual
number doesn’t matter for this analysis.) Another popular proposal
is that debt to GDP ought to be held constant, since it is might be
impossible to know the exact hard ceiling level. (Again, assuming it
exists)
For
simplicity’s sake, let’s assume that the fiscal authority sets
the primary balance to zero in perpetuity. That is, the budget is
balanced excluding interest expenses. To hold debt to GDP constant,
the growth rate of GDP, g, must equal the interest rate, i. This is
true no matter the size of government. Primary spending could be very
high, and set equal to the amount of tax revenue. Conversely, primary
spending could be set to zero and there could be no taxes. In either
case, all interest expenses are paid by issuing more debt. Therefore,
the annual growth rate of the debt stock is simply the interest rate.
The debt to GDP ratio is constant if GDP and debt grow at the same
rate. That is g=i.
Under
this arrangement, the sole determinant of debt sustainability is
monetary policy and growth rates. (Again, primary spending is fixed).
If debt to GDP need only stay below a known danger level, then for
some years g<i is acceptable, so long future years have stronger
growth or lower interest rates, or some combination of the two.
Finally,
although I set the primary budget to zero to keep things simple,
primary deficits, denoted by b, are also possible. The growth rate
of the debt is now just the interest rate plus the primary budget
deficit relative to the size of the existing debt stock, d. That is,
debt to GDP never reaches the danger level if g>= i+b/d
In
modern economies, the interest rate is a policy variable set by
central banks. Therefore, given any fixed path for growth and primary
spending, the monetary authority can always set the interest rate
such that the preferred debt to GDP ratio is reached. (This includes
taking interest rates negative)
Of
course, returning to our second assumption, if the central bank sets
the interest rate to satisfy the debt to GDP constraint, it may have to abandon its inflation target. If a rate of
interest greater than g is required to reach the desired level of
inflation, the central bank faces a difficult trade off. It can let inflation rise above target, or it can allow debt to GDP to exceed
the danger level and accept the accompanying negative economic
consequences. (The exact consequences don’t matter for this
analysis. Usually, budget hawks believe that lower growth and less
investment are the main result)
Under
the first scenario (often described as ‘fiscal dominance’) the
interest rate and therefore inflation has been mapped to fiscal
policy. In other words, a real resource constraint, not a financial
constraint, limits the spending of government provided that it
desires to keep inflation low. This can also be viewed in the
following light. In the long run, g is ultimately limited by the
supply of labor, capital, and technological progress. Since faster
growth would permit higher interest rates without violating the debt
to GDP constraint, and the interest rate is ultimately set with
regard to the path of government spending, the true constraint on
government deficits is the economy’s capacity to produce.
Some
may argue that the central bank might refuse to set the interest rate
such that the debt to GDP ratio is on a sustainable path and instead
focus on delivering low inflation. However, it is crucial bear
in mind that while central banks are independent within government,
they are not independent from government. The decisions to meet a
debt to GDP constraint with budget cuts, tax increases, or changes to
the interest rate all have different distributional issues and are
thus fundamentally political questions. That debate should be had
openly. It should not be swept under the rug by insisting that
changes to the path of primary budget balances are the only way
to stay within the debt to GDP constraint.
Put
another way, if the central bank keeps interest rates above growth
rates in order to combat inflation, the fiscal authority must shift
into primary surplus to keep debt to GDP below the danger level.
Thus, those who lose access to government services (in the case of
spending cuts) or those who pay higher taxes (increased revenues)
bear the cost of controlling inflation. While inflation (and
deflation) also produces winners and losers, it abandons all notions
of equity to assert that concerns about inflation must always trump
the interests of those adversely affected by changes in fiscal
policy.
This
analysis has shown that even if we accept the prevailing view of the
limits of fiscal policy, the mainstream reaches the wrong policy
conclusions. The mainstream insists of ‘getting our fiscal house in
order’ and ‘reigning in spending’ and ‘enhancing revenues.’
However, interest rates, along with taxing and spending, are a large
determinant of the debt to GDP ratio. If it is indeed necessary to
achieve some target for the debt relative to the size of the economy,
it is equally valid to argue for interest rate cuts rather than
fiscal consolidation. This effectively ties monetary policy to fiscal
policy, and thus puts the fiscal authority in effective control of
the price level. The constraint on the budget position is therefore
the acceptable level of inflation. But this is exactly the same
conclusion drawn by heterodox economists, admittedly with a different
set of starting assumptions. While I respect the community of DC
budget wonks as professionals, their analysis is deeply flawed in
that it fails reach the proper conclusion even when their assumptions
are taken as fact.
No comments:
Post a Comment